xxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxxx
Ecuador
This short paper uses the example of a gold miner operating in
Windfall tax is not welcomed by miners
The misconception of guaranteed profits
At first sight, it may seem that as the price of gold (our example metal in this note) rises it would be good news for a miner, even if a windfall tax took away much of the potential profit. Many people assume that if gold moved up from U$1000 to U$1500 an ounce, even though the government would pocket U$350 of the extra U$500 the mining company would still benefit by U$150. Unfortunately that is not the case.
Our example metal of gold is traditionally a good barometer to how inflation affects currencies. Gold (and other commodities) does not suddenly “get expensive” all by itself; gold gets expensive because everything else gets expensive in relation to the currencies we use to buy them, in our case the US dollar. We normally call this phenomenon ‘inflation’. We therefore expect gold to rise as the price of everything else rises in real terms. This theory has proved good recently, as Fig. 1 illustrates.
In the chart below we see that as gold rose approximately 30% in dollar terms through 2007 and so did costs in dollar terms at the established and large gold miner Barrick (ABX). As another example of cost creep, the projected capex needed to build new mines has risen dramatically in this last year, with examples such as the Galore Creek project in Canada (run as a joint venture between Teck Cominco and Novagold), whose projected capex costs rose from under U$2Bn to a whopping U$5Bn in less than 18 months, a cost increase that has halted development at the site completely.
Fig. 1
Price of Gold Influences Production Costs |
||||||
Barrick 4q06 total gold production costs |
$373 |
|||||
Barrick 4q07 total gold production costs |
$482 |
|||||
percentage change |
29.2% |
|||||
Gold price per oz 1st January 2007 |
$639.75 |
|||||
Gold price per oz 31st December 2007 |
$833.75 |
|||||
percentage change |
30.3% |
|||||
source: barrick filings, |
As the price of gold rises, so do the costs of mining the gold (in everything needed to run a mine, including labour, fuel, infrastructure, vehicles etc). We can therefore assume that if gold reached a U$1500/oz, the cost of mining that ounce of gold will not be the same as they would be if gold were at U$1000/oz.
Our model
In the simplified model that follows, we examine how a windfall tax of 70% might affect a gold mining operation.
Parameters
Therefore, in our model we assume the following:
1)
2) As gold rises, costs rise accordingly. In our model the percentage cost of producing gold remains constant to the percentage rise in the price of gold. In the real world there may of course be differences in the comparative price rises, but we are keeping this model simple for the sake of clear illustration.
3) The price of gold rises steadily in the next few years to approach U$2000/oz. The windfall tax therefore kicks in when gold passes U$1000/oz and the burden becomes progressively greater as the price rises.
In the charts below, the blue line represents a company that has low relative costs, and we assume that 50% of gross revenues covers its total production costs (which includes cash cost and other costs not included in the normal cash cost calculation such as sales, admin etc) The green line represents a company with average relative costs, with 60% gross revenues covering its break even point. The black line is a company with relatively high costs and needs 70% of gross revenues to get to break even.
Fig. 2
We see that as the price of gold rises from U$900 to U$2000, the amount of windfall tax due to the government rises accordingly. However costs also rise, and little by little company profitability is crimped between the rise in costs and the rise in windfall payments. In the case of the company with relatively low production costs (blue line), when gold is U$1400/oz or more the company would be less profitable than when it was priced at U$900/oz! A similar but even more depressing story is told by the company with average total production costs (green line). Perhaps the most dramatic is the high total production cost company (black line), who would actually make a loss as gold climbs past U$1700/oz!
The contrast to royalty payments
Now let us examine the same three companies that are obliged to pay a large royalty to the government instead of a windfall tax. In Fig. 3 the royalty is 5% of gross revenues
Fig. 3
In Fig. 4 the royalty is a very large 10% of gross revenues.
Fig. 4
It is clear that, even though a mining company would have to pay more to the state under a royalty agreement as the price of its commodity rose, the company would still benefit from rising profits as the market price increased. This is true even for a 10% royalty on gross revenues, a percentage that would be higher than any other country royalty in the world. As a comparison,
Fig. 5 below compares the three methods of payment outlined in the above charts. We see that until our hypothetical base reference price of U$1000/oz for gold, the windfall tax would bring in no extra revenues while the model royalty system would pay between U$45 and U$100 per ounce of gold. In the U$1200 to U$1400 range, the windfall would produce greater benefits for the state. But as the price of gold passed U$1600 note we have put the windfall charge figures in italics, because from this point onwards it is feasible that some miners will close down operations rather and walk away from a business that offered them an ever diminishing, marginal or even negative return.
Fig. 5
Gold Price per Oz (U$) |
900 |
1000 |
1200 |
1400 |
1600 |
1800 |
2000 |
Gov’t Revenue 70% windfall tax (U$) |
0 |
0 |
140 |
280 |
420 |
560 |
700 |
Gov’t Revenue 5% royalty (U$) |
45 |
50 |
60 |
70 |
80 |
90 |
100 |
Gov’t Revenue 10% royalty (U$) |
90 |
100 |
120 |
140 |
160 |
180 |
200 |
This is the first significant risk with a windfall tax system. If the price of the commodity produced rose to a ‘choke point’, miners start closing up shop. If that happens, everybody loses. The mining company loses revenue and has an idle asset. The employees lose their jobs. The state loses valuable income.
The second significant risk is the lack of investment appeal it makes for those not already in the country. If a mining company wanted to set up a new operation in a foreign land, a potentially inhibitive burden on future earnings such as
Conclusion
Although
President Correa has stated that, “Foreign investment that generates wealth and jobs and pays taxes will always be welcome.”(1), but if President Correa wants new foreign investors to play fair with Ecuador, he should remember that Ecuador must play fair with the foreign investors, else risk losing their revenue or even never seeing them arrive.
(1) http://www.nytimes.com/2006/11/28/world/americas/28ecuador.html